Rural voters in Roman elections

summary

The consensus of modern scholarship is that few Romans voted in elections in the centuriate assembly. Yet this conclusion rests on little evidence. We can gain a clearer picture by looking at the incentives created by the electoral system and Roman social relationships. Focusing on rural citizens of property, this article presents a model of voter behavior and the electoral landscape which reconciles high turnout, the importance of social ties in determining voter choice, and an open, competitive electoral market. Roman elections in the late Republic were perhaps the most complex the world has known.

keywords

Roman Elections, centuriate assembly, Late Republic, voters

when gaius gracchus first stood for the tribunate in 123, "so great a throng poured into the city from the country and took part in the elections that many could not be housed, and since the Campus Martius could not accommodate the multitude, they gave in their voices from the house-tops and tilings" (Plut. C. Gracch. 3.1).1 Contrary to what scholars normally argue, a packed Campus Martius such as this was likely the rule rather than the exception when Romans came together to elect their magistrates. Elections, whether in the tribal or centuriate assembly, drew citizens from all over Italy to the Urbs.

In this article, I present a model of voter behavior and the electoral landscape in the annual centuriate elections, during the period from the introduction of the secret ballot in the 130s to Caesar's dictatorship. My focus is on rural citizens of property down to (approximately) the Fourth Class, a [End Page 127] group which I call the "active centuriate electorate."2 I argue first that these rural citizens traveled to Rome to vote in large numbers, and second that the way they voted was strongly influenced by social ties to the candidates, ties which would usually be indirect, passing through intermediary "men of influence" (homines gratiosi) who served as vote-brokers. All this took place in an electoral landscape that was open and competitive: citizens were able to vote for multiple candidates in each election and lived in a complex social world with many criss-crossing relationships, all of which could be (and routinely were) exploited for electoral purposes. This argument is consistent with our evidence but is not dependent on it. Instead, the model reflects the incentives generated by the electoral system and Roman social relations. These incentives applied to the voters themselves, to the candidates, and to those intermediary brokers of votes and influence whose job it was to "get out the vote." Many voices whispered into each voter's ear: his task was to decide which to listen to.

Put simply, it was in everyone's interest—rural citizens, candidates, and brokers of votes and influence alike—for as many voters as possible from the active centuriate electorate to cast their votes on election day. Crucially, the incentives did not operate equally on all census Classes. I posit an "active centuriate electorate" reaching down to perhaps the Fourth Class; this probably represents a large minority of the adult male citizen population. We cannot hope to give accurate numbers, but even before the Social War we should expect turnout in the high tens of thousands, with this growing to the low hundreds of thousands after the enfranchisement of Italy. This turnout was highest among those citizens whose votes were most valuable, with lower incentives and higher barriers (and thus diminishing turnout) the further down the centuriate Classes we go and the further distance to Rome they had to travel. Moreover, the electoral system did not itself generate disincentives, while obstacles caused by distance and the need for agricultural labor at particular times of the year could often be overcome, particularly when the elections were so attractive.

Finally, I consider the importance of the multiple vote and show how it can reconcile the two pictures of voting behavior normally given in scholarship: on the one hand that "the entire Roman people, both the ruling circle and the mass of voters whom they ruled, was, as a society, permeated by multifarious relationships based on fides and on personal connections" and, on the other hand, that "the electoral power of the broad popular strata … made [End Page 128] it necessary for members of the ruling elite to court and bribe the populace in various ways."3

This is quite a different picture to that now prevailing in scholarship, which is that the mass of citizens had little chance of participating in politics and little interest in it anyway. Rural citizens have been particularly overlooked. Henrik Mouritsen has argued forcefully for "a political process in which only a very small section of the population ever took part."4 For him, most Roman citizens were kept out by their illiteracy, by the restricted space for voting, by the "complex and time-consuming procedures," and by the lack of compensation.5 He also thinks "the 'apolitical' nature of the elections would probably have made the whole exercise an irrelevance to the large majority of the population."6 Moreover, this was not an unfortunate side-effect: "the discrepancy between populus and voters appears to have been an integral and, it would seem, intended feature of the political system."7 Mouritsen here builds on Ramsay MacMullen's 1980 article in Athenaeum; a similar position has been argued by Martin Jehne.8 On what basis do they mount their arguments? MacMullen argues principally from the restricted size of the Saepta (discussed in detail below) and from what he takes to be Rome's intimidating nature to a rural citizen. Jehne accepts what MacMullen and Mouritsen claim about the Saepta, although he is more skeptical about Mouritsen's estimate of the time taken to vote. A rather different (and to my eyes more compelling) picture is presented by Alexander Yakobson: an electoral system with high participation and a real degree of power for the voting citizenry.9 Similar arguments have been advanced by Darryl Phillips and William Rees.10 I largely agree with Yakobson, Phillips, and Rees rather than Mouritsen, but my focus on rural citizens means this article takes a different approach.

the evidence

We must start from one central fact: "ancient authors provide no hard figures for voter turnout or go beyond even the vaguest indication of scale."11 The [End Page 129] evidence we do have is for individual elections and is strongly impressionistic, and hence not particularly useful in discovering how many Roman citizens normally attended. I show below that it cannot be used to argue for low turnout, either regularly or even in the isolated cases for which it has been so used (e.g., in 55 and 45). By the same token, we do have evidence which suggests large crowds at individual elections (e.g., Plut. C. Gracch. 3.1; Cic. Verr. 1.54), and occasions when either all centuries voted (Livy 22.35, 37.47), or almost all (Cic. Brut. 237; Asc. 94C). But these may have been exceptions. The evidence, as a whole, cannot be used to prove (or disprove) either high or low turnout as the normal state of affairs.

Since MacMullen and Mouritsen argue for low turnout largely based on the size of the Saepta, let us consider the evidence. The Saepta, the voting enclosure for elections on the Campus Martius, was a structure approximately 310m long and 120m wide, very probably on the site of the existing Ovile; its northern end lay immediately east of the Pantheon.12 It was planned by Caesar but only completed by Agrippa in 26 (Cic. Att. 4.16.8; Cass. Dio 53.23.2). Voters entered at the northern end, lined up in their tribal pens (from which the joking name ovile or "sheepfold" was derived), and voted at the southern end, after which they departed. Votes were counted in the Diribitorium which adjoined at the southern end. Macmullen argues that the actual voting area could hold at most 55,000 people, which seems reasonable.13 But that does not mean that only 55,000 people could vote in an election held there. As Phillips counters, in a centuriate assembly the Classes voted successively, so the 55,000 figure may only apply to the maximum number of voters in any one class.14 But even this assumes that all voters within a Class would need to be contained within the structure at the same time, which is not the case.

Mouritsen, however, believes the maximum number was much lower, as there would need to be a large forecourt at the northern end to hold those voters waiting to vote. He thinks the segregation of voters was essential to prevent fraud: that is, to stop "those who had already voted from rejoining those still waiting."15 But there is no reason to think so. It might perhaps have been necessary to prevent voters from voting twice in their own Class (although even this seems doubtful and could have been achieved by simply directing voters to leave the area after voting). But Rome entirely lacked the [End Page 130] bureaucratic machinery needed for voter identification; what machinery there was relied on declarations by citizens, which the authorities were rarely in a position to dispute.16 Moreover, the Classes voted sequentially, from richest to poorest, and it seems very unlikely that any Roman would humiliate himself by voting with those beneath him, simply to add his single vote to the hundreds (if not thousands) being cast at the same time. He was especially unlikely to do this in front of people who knew him. It seems similarly unlikely that, for example, voters of the Fourth Class waited in a forecourt, often in midsummer (which is when elections were normally held after Sulla), for the several hours it might take for them to be called on. There is thus no reason to think the size of the voting enclosure was a meaningful restriction on the number of people who voted, either in centuriate or tribal elections. Rather, its great size points to the need to direct and funnel large numbers in a complex procedure over several hours; it is best understood as the response to a problem of movements in space.

There is some literary evidence which has been summoned to argue for low turnout. Mouritsen points to two Ciceronian passages in particular, but these do not have the force he ascribes to them.17 In Pro Plancio 54, Cicero mentions to Laterensis that, in gathering evidence for an ambitus prosecution, he had more witnesses in the Voltinian tribe than he received votes there. Even if we do not read this as straightforward rhetorical exaggeration, it does not actually tell us anything. If, for instance, Laterensis received five votes in this tribe, does that suggest twenty people voted? Or one hundred? Or five thousand? There must have been candidates who performed poorly, especially in particular tribes where they (and their friends) had little influence, or where their competitors had great influence. Cicero's testimony about the election of a suffect consul in 45 is more useful (Fam. 7.30.1):18

In campo certe non fuisti cum hora secunda comitiis quaestori<i>s institutis sella Q. Maximi, quem illi consulem esse dicebant, posita esset; quo mortuo nuntiato sella sublata est. ille autem, qui comitiis tributis esset auspicatus, centuriata habuit, consulem hora septima renuntiavit, qui usque ad Kal. Ian. esset quae erant futurae mane postridie.

At least you were not in the Campus when the elections to the Quaestorship began at nine o'clock in the morning. A chair of state had been placed for Q. Maximus, whom these people used to call Consul. His death was announced, [End Page 131] and the chair removed. Whereupon he, having taken auspices for an assembly of the Tribes, held an assembly of the Centuries, and at one o'clock of the afternoon declared a Consul elected, to remain in office until the Kalends of January, the next morning that was to be.

Nicolet calculates, on the basis of two voters per minute over the five hours Cicero mentions, a voting crowd of 16,800, all from the first two Classes.19 Mouritsen, however, notes problems with this calculation: due to the short mid-winter days, Cicero's five hours were really only three hours and forty-five minutes, while the reorganization into centuries of a crowd originally convening for a tribal assembly would have taken additional time.20 So Mouritsen reasons a quarter of the time was lost and, with the uneven size of the voting tribes, calculates 6,000 voters in the first two Classes. This is perhaps an underestimate but, far from pointing to low turnout, actually suggests numbers were normally large. The circumstances of this election were, after all, highly unusual. It was originally meant to be a quaestorian election in the tribal assembly (i.e., not organized by Classes), so presumably upper-Class voters would not have turned up in disproportionately large numbers. So the 6,000 voters of the first two Classes might have been, on a conservative estimate, one-third of all who attended. If we can estimate that 18,000 voters showed up for a quaestorian election, at the end of December (when it was probably very cold) under Caesar's dictatorship, that suggests the turnout for a consular election, in better weather, and in the days of the libera res publica would have been much higher.

We also need to consider the Commentariolum Petitionis and what it suggests about the scale and nature of elections.21 Following most recent scholars, I accept it as genuine, or at least as giving an authentic and well-informed picture of electoral campaigns in the 60s.22 The work gives no indication of voter turnout but does suggest a very complex electoral landscape. Moreover, while in this article I am presenting the electoral system from the propertied rural voter's perspective, the Commentariolum Petitionis shows it from the candidate's perspective. Strength in both friends and public reputation was essential for victory (section 16), although Tatum suggests cogently this is a conventional distinction (compare Cic. Att. 1.1.2) because it is in practice [End Page 132] muddied in the rest of the treatise.23 Overall the treatise suggests candidates saw only radical uncertainty: the electorate was too large, complex, and unpredictable to manage. The treatise definitely does not suggest, in MacMullen's words, that "politics was ordinarily a cozy business."24 More relevant to this article, the Commentariolum Petitionis indicates candidates needed to win over country voters, and the way to do this was through men influential in the municipia (24, 30–31).25 The political scene was littered with groups and organizations with electoral importance, such as the four sodalities Cicero had won to his side by defending their members (19); these groups were evidently important structures for channeling votes. Beyond this, there were also "men eager for advancement [who] have worked very hard, with unreserved eagerness and energy, to be able to get what they want from their fellow tribesmen" (18); this was clearly a development which was both recent and not (yet) comprehensive. Still, it points to the central importance of the tribes as electoral units. Moreover, a candidate needed to create a broad coalition of relatively small, independent pockets of support in many different tribes to win.26

voting procedure and the census classes

Consuls and praetors were elected in the centuriate assembly; curule aediles, quaestors and minor magistrates in the tribal assembly. In both cases the thirty-five tribes were the basis of the voting units.27 In the tribal assembly there were only the thirty-five tribal voting units. The centuriate assembly was much more complex, as voters were split horizontally (by census Class) as well as vertically (by tribe).28 This meant the tribe was the key unit: to win the election, candidates had to win whole tribes, not just groups of voters within [End Page 133] them. So far, the Roman system is intelligible to voters in a parliamentary system, if we think of the candidates as equivalent to modern parties and the voting units as constituencies.29 The order in which the Classes were called to vote was not strictly hierarchical; equites voted perhaps with, or more probably after, the First Class.

The procedure for voting is also reasonably well known, although it is complex.30 For the sake of clarity, let us imagine a hypothetical consular election in which there are two consuls to be elected. The same principles and methods applied to praetorian elections (with six or, after Sulla, eight vacancies). Each voter could vote for two candidates (six or eight in a praetorian election); this is the principle of the multiple vote which is of central importance in this article.31 Within each voting unit, the two candidates who attracted the most votes were that unit's choice, without weighting. That is, in a hypothetical century of 100 voters (= 200 votes) who gave 100 votes to Cicero, 51 to Antonius and 49 to Catiline, the century's votes were simply for Cicero and Antonius.32 Once a candidate received the votes of a majority of the centuries (97 out of 193), he was declared elected. When two candidates reached this point and thus both places were filled, the election was at an end, and no further Classes were called to vote.

With only the Second Class being needed for a majority, it is uncertain how often the lower Classes would be required to vote. This is important in calculating the balance of incentives for such voters to make the journey and for others to help them to do so. We do know of elections in which one candidate won by only a few centuries and thus in which the lower Classes certainly voted. In 64 Antonius pauculis centuriis Catilinam superavit (Asc. 94C), while (possibly) the previous year L. Turius lost by only a few centuries (Cic. Brut. 237) and Q. Metellus Macedonicus won only narrowly in 143, after [End Page 134] two repulsae (De vir. ill. 61.3). There are also examples in Livy of not all the places being filled in one day and a second round of voting being required (22.35, 37.47); in such cases all Classes must have voted. But we face here the same problem as elsewhere: were such elections the rule or the exception? Arguments based on the time voting must have taken do not help us much, because we have little detailed knowledge of the Roman procedure (which was on such a larger scale than that envisaged by the Flavian municipal laws that the evidence of the latter is of little help).33 We might interpret the move of elections to July (tentatively dated to Sulla) as a result of the need for the fourteen hours of daylight Rome offers at that time of year. Yakobson argues, with suitable diffidence in view of the lack of evidence, that the lower Classes probably were often called to vote.34 Elections were, after all, contests between elite candidates, with resources of similar kind and magnitude; bribery was targeted to win whole centuries. These factors were likely to split the votes of centuries in the upper census Classes, meaning the lower Classes would be decisive.35 Of course, the Third Class was more likely to vote than the Fourth, and the Fourth more likely than the Fifth. And, mathematically, praetorian elections were more likely to split the vote, with more candidates to be elected and without a centuria praerogativa to guide the voters. So, since we are concerned here with the balance of incentives for rural voters to travel to Rome, the confidence that the journey would not be wasted was stronger for those in the Third Class than in the Fifth. But it seems to me likely that a Fourth Class voter, whatever the strength of other incentives, could be reasonably confident of voting in at least one of the consular or praetorian elections. Hence, for the purposes of this article, I suggest the active centuriate electorate comprised the first four census Classes. This gives us something to work with, as long as we remember it is approximate: we are here in the realm of a balance of incentives and disincentives. [End Page 135]

Yet such considerations only applied in the centuriate assembly. In the tribal assembly, citizens voted by tribe only, so census Class did not matter. And it seems that, normally, elections for curule aedile, quaestor, and the minor magistracies in the tribal assembly were held in the days immediately after elections for consul and praetor in the centuriate assembly. Therefore, voters in rural tribes from the Third or Fourth Classes knew they would be called to vote in tribal elections and would quite likely (though not certainly) be called to vote in at least one of the consular or praetorian elections. A journey to Rome to vote would not be wasted.

When we speak of men of the Fourth Class as against the First, what type of socio-economic distinction do we mean? And how many of each type of voter were there? This steers us into the question of Roman demography, a contentious topic.36 Clearly, the Social War and the enfranchisement of Italy deeply altered the Roman electorate: it became much larger and probably poorer on average, while the tribal map of Italy was massively overhauled. But the qualifications for each Class do not seem to have changed within our period. For the First Class, the amount was property worth either HS40,000 or HS25,000; I will use the larger figure here as the more conservative for my purposes.37 The figures for the Second, Third, and Fourth Classes were, respectively, 75%, 50%, and 25% of the First Class qualification. What size farm do such amounts describe, understanding that the census rating included all property, including farm buildings, equipment, livestock, and slaves? Rathbone suggests the First Class census represented (notionally) 100 iugera of land (about 25 ha), while Rees (following Duncan-Jones) estimates an average land value of around HS475–660 per iugerum.38 However, as Rees notes himself, this might be too low. We should expect land that was fertile, close to Rome, or close to the sea, navigable rivers or major roads to be more expensive. This description covers a great deal of the ager Romanus before the Social War. Rees estimates that a farmer with "50 iugera, a house and possibly an ox would have more than HS25,000 at the lowest price estimate."39 Adapting this to a HS40,000 qualification and a higher cost of land, we can say that an 80-iugera farm, with accompanying equipment, would place its owner comfortably in the First Class. A farm of 20 iugera would be a Fourth Class rating. The income from such farms might be estimated in the hundreds to low thousands of sesterces per year; this should be remembered when we come to consider [End Page 136] the incentives to go to Rome for the elections. In any case, to a senator with estates worth a million sesterces, a First Class voter worth HS50,000 and a Third Class voter worth HS25,000 would have seemed equally poor.

The significant improvement in survey archaeology in recent decades has caused scholars to rethink the economy of ancient Italy.40 While there is significant disagreement, the overall picture for the last two centuries b.c.e. is one of (modest) economic growth, diversity of agriculture driven by urban markets (Rome especially, but also smaller regional cities), and the empire relieving Italy of the need to concentrate on grain. There was some growth in villas, but probably not at the expense of small farms.41 Small farms could still be owned by large landowners and run by tenants; these would not appear as voters and cannot be shown clearly in the archaeological record.42 Moreover, the presence of small farmhouses with ornate mosaic floors does not by itself suggest ownership rather than tenancy.43 While (as noted above) Rees argues for land values in the range HS475–660 per iugerum, this would only be true for arable land. But Italy was clearly a highly diverse agricultural economy, which included the raising of cash crops (and livestock such as game) for the market. Such agricultural practices could generate large incomes (and correspondingly high land values) on small plots of land. Kron points to the Villa Regina at Boscoreale, where a vineyard of 7–10 iugera, able to be worked by a single family, could possibly generate revenues of HS7,000.44 We might compare Varro's friend's farm of 200 iugera at Reate, which generated an annual revenue of HS30,000 (RR 3.2.15). This should be understood in conjunction with a probable rise in the price of land from the second century onwards, and with the lex agraria of 111 which made more land private and so both able to be sold and able to be counted as personal wealth for census purposes.45

This leads us to ask, how many rural citizens fitted into the active centuriate electorate? Here we are on very contentious ground and can give no certain answers. The equestrian census in the Augustan period was HS400,000. We do not know for sure whether it was already at that figure before Augustus, but Davenport is suitably conservative in saying the figure must have been higher than it was for the First Class rating, which in turns means "the first [End Page 137] property-class must in any case have been several times larger than the equestrian order in the broad sense of the term."46 And we know there were thousands of equites in the early first century, because at least that many were proscribed by Sulla (App. BCiv. 1.95). At the other end of the socio-economic spectrum, Rosenstein argues that there were few proletarii at the time of the Second Punic War.47 This all points to the active centuriate electorate of the first four census Classes being, at least, a large minority of the citizen body, some hundreds of thousands of men. Most of these were surely rural citizens. The comitia centuriata was not controlled by a tiny elite. Thus the question of whether "more than 10% of the adult male citizenry voted in any consular election" misses the more interesting question of who voted.48

Rural voters of property knew their vote, and thus their presence in Rome, was valuable. As we shall see below, this fact shaped not only their decision to come, but whether it was worth others' efforts to facilitate that journey. It also shaped the behavior of candidates. It was likely but not certain that the middle and lower Classes would vote in any one year, so a prudent candidate would need to hedge his bets and attract middle and lower Class voters.49 As attested close elections show (such as those of 143, 65, and 64 noted above), such voters could very easily decide the result. These voters were not, man for man, as valuable as those in the equestrian centuries or the First Class: there were more people in the middle and lower Classes, concentrated in fewer voting units. But that did not make them unimportant.50 This vast size and complexity of the electorate, together with uncertainty about whose vote would count in any one year and how much, all contributed to the unpredictability which our sources depict: the electorate was often compared to a billowing and unpredictable sea which created anxiety in candidates (e.g., Cic. Mur. 35–36, Planc. 11, 15).

incentives and obstacles

While the number of potential voters gives us some idea of the scale and nature of an election, it can only be a vague guide. Yet I have already argued [End Page 138] that the evidence, such as we have it, cannot be used to prove either high or low turnout; it is suggestive at best, and no individual election for which we have evidence can be shown to be typical. A different approach is needed, one which examines the incentives operating on rural voters. Therefore, for the remainder of this article, I concentrate on the incentives and disincentives which governed whether rural citizens with property, especially those who lived at a distance from Rome, would come to the elections as well as how those incentives influenced the way they would vote. These were the incentives generated by the electoral system itself, in its interaction with the structures of Roman society. I argue that potential disincentives to travel could often be quite easily overcome. By their nature, my arguments are general. They apply primarily to what I have called the active centuriate electorate, although most strongly to voters of the First Class and least to those of the Fourth. Apart from ordinary citizens, I consider men of influence: influence over the tribes when they came to Rome and influence over voters in the rural towns of Italy. These are the men who Quintus Cicero refers to in a specifically electoral context as the gratiosi (Comment. Pet. 19, 24; cf. Cic. Mur. 47). At the lower end, these gratiosi in rural Italy were the local focus of loyalty for their humbler neighbors and the vital mediators between senators in Rome and voters on the land.51 When those rural voters weighed whether or not to go to Rome, what did they consider? What might dissuade them from the journey?

Most obviously, Rome might be a long way away: by the later second century, Roman citizens lived as far away as Parma in the north. Nevertheless, they were in the minority. Before Italian enfranchisement, most Roman territory lay along the two great routes out of the City, either north on the via Flaminia or south-east on the via Appia and via Latina. Laurence argues that groups of travelers on foot could manage 50–60km per day on the major roads, although I prefer to be more conservative and adopt ORBIS's "private" speed of 36km per day.52 Few people in the middle Tiber valley lived more than a couple of kilometres from a paved road, while most of the pre-Social War ager Romanus was less than two hours' walk from a road or river.53 Those new citizens added after the Social War were not as well connected to Rome by road and were probably, on average, poorer. They also lacked the habit [End Page 139] of voting in Rome (and, at first, the social connections encouraging them to do so). Some rebel areas and societies had been badly devastated during the fighting of the 80s.54 All this suggests they were somewhat less likely to vote than the older citizens. Therefore, even if the overall citizen population doubled (as the census figures suggest), the number of regular voters probably increased by a smaller amount. All this meant that, according to ORBIS, almost all who lived in the pre-Social War citizen territory closer than the ager Gallicus could reach Rome in less than four days. A journey by road from Ariminum would take eight days, compared to fifteen from Brundisium and sixteen from Mediolanum. But we know that, in the sixties and fifties at least, Cisalpine Gaul was electorally very important.55 Cicero made a special point of joining the governor's staff in 65 to help his consular campaign because videtur in suffragiis multum posse Gallia ("Gaul looks like counting heavily in the voting"; Cic. Att. 1.1.2).56 Cisalpine voters were of great importance to Caesar in the later fifties, supporting both Antony's augural campaign and (he hoped) Labienus in his prospective consular campaign ([Caes.] BGall. 8.50, 52). And a few years later, Cicero looked back on the days when "we" consular candidates used to canvass the province's coloniae and municipia (Cic. Phil. 2.76); he presents this as routine practice.57 So if Cisalpine voters would normally make it to Rome in such numbers that they were worth the time and effort of consular candidates, then presumably this would also be true for those areas much closer to the City.

Moreover, people in Roman Italy were used to traveling; we should not regard a lengthy journey as itself a major disincentive unless it prevented necessary work. Farm produce had to be brought to market.58 Military service and attendance at the census required journeys. Travel was part of the life experience of most Roman citizens.59 Our perception of the inconvenience of multi-day travel is skewed by our own experience of airplanes and fast trains which allow us to travel across the world in barely a day (a journey with which southern hemisphere academics are particularly familiar). But compared to [End Page 140] the journey to Spain or Cilicia (which could take months), spending two to three weeks traveling would not in itself be regarded as a major inconvenience. This was particularly true when travel could bring financial benefit.

Life as a farmer required a lot of work, so one might object that the need for agricultural labor would prevent voters from leaving home. It might, but only in some circumstances. Roman Italy was characterized by mixed farming, with cereals much the most important crop. However, while farming was certainly labor-intensive, there was little work that had to be done at a specific time; most could be brought forward, delayed, or spread out if less labor was available.60 In such circumstances, it would not be difficult for the head of the household to leave his wife, children, and slaves to mind the farm, although here again the obstacles were lowest for those further up the Class hierarchy, with their greater means allowing more slaves to be kept and laborers to be hired.61 The exception was the harvest, which, for grain, began at or after midsummer and might continue into August. The harvest needed all available labor in order to get in the crop before bad weather struck.62 This corresponded with the date of the consular elections after Sulla, which were frequently held in July.63 The effect (and perhaps the intention) would have been to make it difficult for small farmers to attend—at least when the civil and solar calendars were synchronized, as they frequently were not. This was also the case for Ti. Gracchus's attempt to be re-elected tribune in the summer of 133, when the harvest prevented his rural supporters from attending (App. BCiv. 1.14.1). Any elections held at harvest-time would therefore be much more poorly attended. However, if harvests were gathered before the elections, then the need to bring grain to market might be a powerful additional spur to come to Rome. But harvests were not a factor in the later second century when (it appears) elections were still normally held towards the end of the year, in November or December. Overall, then, the timing of elections in relation to the harvest could affect voter turnout. But as timing was inconsistent, the effects varied.

Were there politicians who exercised such control over a voting tribe as to turn it into a "pocket borough"—that is, to simply designate a handful of [End Page 141] voters to implement their will? Or, alternatively, were any powerful forces able to successfully discourage or prevent voters from attending elections, as with "voter suppression" in the contemporary United States? These are two separate problems but amount to the same outcome: the number of voters being controlled (or at least strongly curtailed) by pauci potentes.64 We have no positive evidence for this happening. Moreover, if it did happen, we should expect references in the sources to some tribes being predictable: winning those tribes would be a matter of winning over their boss, rather than appealing to the voters themselves. But while we do see men of influence in certain tribes, there is no indication in our evidence of anyone with that type of power; indeed, the whole tenor of our evidence is against it, at least in the Ciceronian period.65 Carrying any tribe was a difficult and uncertain business, which could be explained in retrospect (as Cicero claims he can do at Planc. 48) but not easily arranged in advance. Tribes were too big and too amorphous for any one political boss to control them. As Taylor shows, by the second century, the majority of tribes had multiple discontinuous areas, and most of the remainder were very large.66 Everything we know of Roman society argues against local magnates having this sort of control over their freeborn neighbors. Moreover, there were substantial incentives for voters to go to Rome (see below). Any influential man depriving them of these incentives would need powerful levers of his own, whether carrot or stick. We see this lack of control in 53–52: Clodius opposed Milo's campaign by delay, bribery, and supporting his opponents rather than by trying to exclude his supporters (Cic. Mil. 25; Asc. 30–31C). Similarly, Verres tried to prevent Cicero's election to the aedileship by bribery rather than any other means (Cic. Verr. 1.22–23, 25). Compare also Planc. 54, in which the possibility is raised of voters being bribed not to vote for a certain candidate; in practice, this was achieved by having them vote for another. If any candidate, trying to shore up his own support in a tribe, wanted to keep out certain voters, then his competitors (not to mention candidates in elections for other offices) would correspondingly want them to come. The multiple vote and lack of party tickets meant that Roman elections were not a zero-sum game. We must reject the idea of powerful political actors keeping voters away.

One might object to this picture by pointing to Comment. Pet. 18, where Quintus refers to men who have, or expect to have, control over a tribe or [End Page 142] century, or to Cic. Fam. 11.16.3 where Dec. Brutus is supposed to have this power over some centuries of the equites. This is answered by the multiple vote, discussed in more detail below. Influential men might well have enough clout to ensure a particular candidate was one of the two, or eight, chosen by a particular tribal unit, but this is a long way from completely controlling the unit. Victory for one candidate did not automatically mean defeat for another.

The elections were potentially a lucrative event for many voters. Most obvious is the prospect of cash bribery by candidates, although we have very few indications of the scale of bribery. Those we do have come from the later fifties and are clearly much higher than normal: in 54 the centuria praerogativa was allegedly promised ten million sesterces to elect Memmius and Domitius (Cic. QFr. 2.15.4), while in 52 Milo tried to counteract his unpopularity by distributing HS250 per head tributim (Asc. 35C; this was in addition to money distributed the previous year). Clearly, the amounts on offer were not ordinarily large. But if a voter remained for the aedilician elections he could vote for, and so honorably accept money from, twelve different candidates: small bribes from each could accumulate into something quite substantial. And there were more benefits a voter might receive from all the candidates, not only those he intended to vote for: banquets, shows, seats at the shows, distributions of oil or food.67 Other nobles might distribute largesse too, either as friends of the candidates or with an eye to their own future prospects (see e.g., Cic. Mur. 73). Election campaigns were one of the primary ways by which the wealth of the empire, mostly seized by the ruling class, trickled down to the mass of Roman citizens. Furthermore, for men whose annual income might only be measured in the hundreds of sesterces, the money on offer was likely to at the very least offset the costs of the journey and might go well beyond that.

We also need to understand the elections as a social occasion, bringing people together from across Italy (Cic. Verr. 1.54). Voters could renew relationships with people from all over the peninsula. Not only could this be a pleasure in itself but it also facilitated the transaction of all sorts of business: property deals, arranging marriages, clearing up disputed inheritances, and more. At a general level, the elections would themselves contribute to the economic integration of Italy by bringing so many of the principal wealth holders together in one place each year. While elections may not have directly been responsible for the movement of many goods, they were an excellent occasion for exchanging information and doing deals. Because the elections were a major social event, they were a major economic event too. These travelers' experience of Rome was not of a place "bigger, noisier, more jostling and in [End Page 143] every way more strange and hostile than any other town in the experience of the ordinary Italian," because the average rural voter would not encounter the City alone.68 He was probably traveling with a group from home: the incentives which brought voters to Rome operated on a large scale and would draw in many men from every community. Finally, there were the psychological benefits, encountering what Martin Jehne calls aristocratic Jovialität.69 In no other sphere of life could ordinary citizens expect nobiles to solicit their affection.

social network incentives

The most important incentives were those arising from social networks. The basic importance of reciprocity in Roman social relations is well known: it was a positive social value at all levels. As argued below, voting was an essential favor that citizens could do for others in their social networks, and the fact that they disposed of many votes meant they could do many favors. Moreover, this social fact applied to everyone (within the active centuriate electorate) in a given voter's social network, meaning that not only did incentives operate on voters as individuals, but operated on entire networks, and so acted more strongly. Simply put, a voter's relatives and neighbors all wanted him to vote as well. The act of voting in the elections was the essential act in what we may rightly, following Wallace-Hadrill, call a "patronage network" understood by the Romans using the language of friendship and fides.70 These incentives were not one-offs but recurred each year, with each new election cycle. The individual candidates may have changed, but the fact that there were candidates remained the same, and these new candidates enjoyed much the same place in society, and operated within the same social networks, as the previous ones. That meant they sought votes from these same networks, and in the same way: the social network incentives to vote were therefore permanent, structural features of the electoral system.71 The incentive for voters to come to Rome in groups and vote was always present.

Scholarship on Roman elections normally adopts the point of view of candidates. This is to be expected: our evidence generally and the Commentariolum [End Page 144] Petitionis in particular are written from their point of view. So far I have tried to give the voters' perspective. But the direct connection between candidates and voters, whether understood as a social relationship or a projected image, was not the only relationship. There were also intermediaries, who greatly complicated the picture. Following the Commentariolum Petitionis (19, 24, 29), I refer to these intermediaries collectively as homines gratiosi, "influential men" and I schematize them as being at two levels: the lower, working locally in direct connection to voters, and the upper, working centrally with direct connection to candidates. Their function (at the upper end of the spectrum) was to deliver to candidates the votes of centuries or tribes. These upper gratiosi included senators and their sons and politically active equites (Comment. Pet. 33).72 This is, I believe, the meaning of an obscure passage at Comment. Pet. 18:73

Ad conficiendas centurias, homines excellenti gratia. Qui abs te tribum aut centuriam aut aliquod beneficium aut habeant aut ut habeant sperent, eos prorsus magno opere et compara et confirma; nam per hos annos homines ambitiosi vehementer omni studio atque opera elaborarunt ut possent a tribulibus suis ea quae peterent impetrare.

For delivering the votes of the centuries, men of exceptional influence. It is imperative that you recruit and retain those men who, on account of you, have, or expect to have, control over a tribe or a century, or some other advantage. For, in recent years, men eager for advancement have worked very hard, with unreserved eagerness and energy, to be able to get what they want from their fellow tribesmen.

Most senators had been or would be candidates for office and so had recently devoted considerable efforts to cultivating the electorate. The relationships and up-to-date political knowledge so acquired were not for their own use alone; they could be made available to friends (Cic. Planc. 45). A good, if oblique, example is Cic. Att. 2.1.9: Favonius meam tribum tulit honestius quam suam, Luccei perdidit ("Favonius carried my tribe with greater credit than his own, but lost Lucceius'"). Shackleton Bailey plausibly suggests this refers to Lucceius's unsuccessful support of Favonius's candidature (for tribune?): in this interpretation, Lucceius was supporting Favonius, and so the failure of his tribe to vote for Favonius reflected badly on both men. Lucceius would himself contest the consular elections only a few weeks later, so his visibility and influence among the tribes was at its height.74 Mutual electoral support was [End Page 145] thus much of the currency of senatorial politics. This support, surely, is what Quintus means by "favors done, the expectation of future favors" (Comment. Pet. 21), at least for those senators who did not have tremendous oratorical gifts to offer.75 This is equivalent to the role the "economy of friends" played in financing senatorial careers, with one exception: in giving and repaying electoral support, what was "spent" was not necessarily lost, but perhaps even augmented.76

Also relevant are the coitiones (electoral compacts between candidates) mentioned at Cic. Planc. 53–54.77 These deal with specific tribes: Plancius allegedly "conceded" his own Teretina to Laterensis, and Plotius the Aniensis tribe to Pedius. While this was an extension of the idea of cultivating support for a friend it was quite different in effect: these men were rival candidates. Yet we can reconstruct the reasoning behind such arrangements. Perhaps Laterensis similarly "conceded" to Plancius another tribe in which he was influential, in which case each had picked up a tribe, or perhaps Plancius hoped by this manoeuvre to squeeze out a stronger candidate. In any event, the multiple vote (on which see more below) allowed this to be a mutually beneficial arrangement. The closest modern analogy is political parties with a common enemy agreeing not to run candidates in constituencies where they might split the vote, as was allegedly discussed between Labour and the Liberal Democrats in the UK's 2019 General Election.

Beyond those influential in Rome, there was a lower stratum of intermediaries, the locally influential men in the municipia across Italy. Comment. Pet. 32 nicely differentiates these two levels of gratiosi, between those who can exert influence over whole tribes and those who merely wield influence over some part of a tribe. The role of these local grandees can, I think, be understood most clearly if we conceive of votes in economic terms, with reciprocal favors being the currency.78 Votes were a commodity, an asset owned by the voters, and very much in demand by candidates; this demand was a constant, recurring every year. We would, therefore, expect a mechanism to develop to match demand to supply. Votes flowed up this mechanism, from ordinary rural voters at the bottom to candidates at the top; favors flowed down. Starting at the local level, by voting as asked voters could win or repay favors from locally [End Page 146] important connections, those men influential in their district or municipium. By mobilizing votes, these local grandees could, in turn, win favors from those higher up the social scale, and so forth up the ladder. Of course, this schematizes what must have been an incredibly complex network of influence, with every man of influence probably working for multiple candidates with a greater or lesser degree of zeal. The Commentariolum Petitionis shows us the difficulty and importance of motivating such men (and women). But in all cases, the end result must have been the delivery of the votes in question to the elections in Rome. Only then were the favors actually worth anything. This in turn meant that it was in everyone's interest—the candidates, the gratiosi, and the voters themselves—to make it as easy as possible to deliver the vote.

I define the gratiosi here as a function rather than a social group: that function was brokering votes, or blocs of votes, in exchange for favors. That this function was a structural feature of the electoral system needs emphasis; there were, of course, no political parties in Rome, but what I describe here is similar to a modern party machine. It was a permanent structure of political life. We see some glimpses of this structure in the evidence, most notably in the Commentariolum Petitionis and the Pro Plancio (cf. Cic. Har. Resp. 42). The terms involved are familiar in scholarship: divisores, sodalitates, sequestres, and the like.79 We know these held electoral importance, and it is clear that the terms used carried a heavy moral load, differing depending on who was speaking. It is likely, for instance, that the "men eager for advancement [who] have worked very hard, with unreserved eagerness and energy, to be able to get what they want from their fellow tribesmen" (Comment. Pet. 18: homines ambitiosi vehementer omni studio atque opera elaborarunt ut possent a tribulibus suis ea quae peterent impetrare—and note the positive or at least neutral tone used to characterize such men) are the same as, or at least heavily overlap with, the (clearly disreputable) sequestres and divisores mentioned at section 57, who are to be intimidated and made afraid. It is therefore fruitless to search for the "legitimate" and "illegitimate" functions of sodalitates or divisores. We would do better to understand that every important social relationship in Rome could be and was turned to electoral ends.

the multiple vote

All this talk of the influence that gratiosi exercised over ordinary voters is reminiscent of what John North memorably called the "frozen waste" theory of Roman politics.80 A reader would be justified in asking how it can be reconciled [End Page 147] with the picture of an open, competitive electoral market painted by Yakobson (a picture I agree with). The answer is by the multiple vote, a sadly understudied aspect of the Roman electoral system. The multiple vote is the final piece of the puzzle.

If my picture of the incentives operating on voters is accepted, then these voters would have arrived in Rome with committed votes. But not all their votes would already be strongly committed; in the post-Sullan period, each voter could vote for, and thus honor, two consular candidates, eight praetorian candidates, and two curule aediles, not to mention quaestors and (if plebeian elections happened to be coordinated with those for magistracies of the populus) tribunes and plebeian aediles. Unlike in most modern electoral systems, Roman voters did not face an either/or choice. Instead, they were choosing (perhaps) twelve individual candidates from a larger pool to give their votes; in this way, the Roman system recalls modern multi-member constituencies, but with the crucial difference of the absence of parties.81 Therefore, even if rural voters were responding to social network pressures, as discussed above, they still retained some freedom in disposing of their remaining votes.

This is best shown by examining a hypothetical voter, Q. Vibius (a name attested at Venafrum in imperial inscriptions). Vibius is a farmer of the Second Class, from Venafrum, in the Volturnus valley near where Latium runs into Campania, and of the tribe Teretina. He has come to Rome at the behest of a group of local equites, major landowners in the area, to vote for two particular praetorian candidates and one consular candidate. But he has nine more votes to bestow in the consular, praetorian, and aedilician elections, and he only decides these votes in Rome. He is more committed to some than others, and so the lead offered by the centuria praerogativa sways him to an extent (on which, see more below). But a man from nearby Atina is standing for the aedileship, and the claims of vicinitas are strong (Cic. Planc. 21). Vibius's cousin recently served in Spain, and spoke highly of a praetorian candidate who had commanded troops there as a legatus (note how Cicero emphasizes the persuasiveness of soldiers' recommendations at Mur. 38). The uncle of Vibius's wife is canvassing widely for another praetorian candidate, while the agent of yet another candidate has promised ten denarii to everyone in Vibius's century if it should choose him; this candidate also staged famously lavish games as an aedile. One of the consular candidates impressed Vibius greatly by shaking his hand on the via Sacra and calling him by name. Vibius has recently received a timely favor from an acquaintance in Puteoli, and so [End Page 148] he is anxious to repay the debt by voting for the candidate that man supports. These are just hypotheticals, but they suggest how complex was the social web in which rural Roman citizens lived their lives, and the manifold ways in which the strings of that web could be tugged for electoral purposes. And if this complexity enmeshed rural voters, it also enmeshed the gratiosi who sought to influence them. In choosing who to vote for, a voter was deciding which voices to listen to, out of the many speaking into his ear.

This perhaps explains the role of the centuria praerogativa, a single century of the First Class which was chosen by lot to vote (and have its vote announced) before the rest of the assembly. According to Cicero, the candidate the centuria praerogativa chose first was always elected either that year or the following year (Planc. 49). Other examples from republican history attest to its importance (e.g., Cic. Mur. 38; Livy 24.7–9). It has variously been interpreted as ominous, showing Jupiter's will, or alternatively as a conscious mechanism to produce more random and decisive electoral outcomes, in order to minimize the importance of campaigning.82 But in view of the model I have put forward in this article, it is best interpreted as having a bandwagon effect, by giving a guide to uncommitted or weakly committed voters which way to direct their vote. In any case, we should not overstate its importance. As Mouritsen says, "towards the end of the republic the praerogativa may have given little more than a general boost to the authority of its chosen candidate, improving his chances now or in the future"; it was no longer true, if it had ever been, that "the outcome of the election could be predicted as soon as its vote had been declared."83 And in consular elections with only three or four serious candidates, of various strengths, we should expect a candidate who received the most votes in a particular century to usually be elected. So the centuria praerogativa should be understood as yet another voice speaking to a voter, but in this case telling him what his fellow citizens were thinking.

The end result of all this was an electoral landscape that was exceedingly complex, certainly more complex than any known in the modern world, where the existence of political parties has made for much more structured elections. The secret ballot, introduced in the 130s, both speeded up the process of voting and made campaigning much more opaque. Candidates and gratiosi could not know for sure to what extent their efforts with particular voters had borne fruit. But this complexity also allows us to reconcile the two theories which have dominated modern scholarship on Roman elections: that they were a "frozen wasteland" dominated by private social ties between [End Page 149] candidates and voters, and that the electoral market was free and voters had to be won over by reputation, magnificence, and cash. While it is not fruitful to use the terms "patron" and "client," social ties between candidates and voters did exist and did shape voter behavior—as long as we recognize that these social ties were immensely complex and passed through many intermediaries. Rather than being bound in chains of dependence, a more useful metaphor is of citizens enmeshed in webs of social ties, of all sorts. Because voters were subject to social pressures from many directions, and because they had multiple votes at their disposal, they had to choose which pressures to respond to. This meant that candidates could not simply rely on their social connections: such connections had to be worked. Other resources had to be deployed, too: magnificent games, military reputations, direct or conditional bribes. But even these are best understood as additional threads in the web, which cumulatively decided which way voters in the Campus Martius would turn on election day.

David Rafferty
The University of Adelaide

works cited

Bispham, E. 2007. From Asculum to Actium: The Municipalization of Italy from the Social War to Augustus. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Coarelli, F. 2001. "Les 'Saepta' et la technique du vote à Rome de la fin de la République à Auguste." Pallas 55: 37–51.
Cox, G. W. 1984. "Strategic Electoral Choice in Multi-Member Districts: Approval Voting in Practice?" AJPS 28: 722–38. doi: 10.2307/2110996.
Davenport, C. 2019. A History of the Roman Equestrian Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
de Haas, T. 2017. "The Geography of Roman Italy and Its Implications for the Development of Rural Economies." In de Haas and Tol, eds. 51–82.
de Haas, T. and Tol, G. eds. 2017. The Economic Integration of Roman Italy: Rural Communities in a Globalizing World. Leiden: Brill.
de Ligt, L. and Northwood, S. 2008. People, Land, and Politics: Demographic Developments and the Transformation of Roman Italy 300 BC–AD 14. Leiden: Brill.
Erdkamp, P. 2008. "Mobility and Migration in Italy in the Second Century BC." In de Ligt and Northwood, eds. 417–49.
Feig Vishnia, R. 2012. Roman Elections in the Age of Cicero: Society, Government, and Voting. New York: Routledge.
Gelzer, M. 1969. The Roman Nobility. Trans. by R. Seager. Oxford: Blackwell.
Goodchild, H. 2007. "Modelling Roman agricultural production in the middle Tiber valley, central Italy." PhD, University of Birmingham, UK.
Hall, U. 1964. "Voting Procedure in Roman Assemblies." Historia 3: 267–306.
———. 1998. "'Species libertatis': Voting Procedure in the Late Roman Republic." BICS 42: 15–30.
Hölkeskamp, K-J. 2010. Reconstructing the Roman Republic: An Ancient Political Culture and Modern Research. Trans. by H. Heitmann-Gordon. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Isayev, E. 2017. Migration, Mobility and Place in Ancient Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jehne, M. 2000. "Jovialität und Freiheit. Zur Institutionalität der Beziehungen zwischen Ober- und Unterschichten in der römischen Republik." In Linke, B. and Stemmler, M. eds. Mos maiorum. Untersuchungen zu den Formen der Identitätsstiftung und Stabilisierung in der römischen Republik. Stuttgart: Steiner. 207–35.
———. 2006. "Who Attended Roman Assemblies? Some Remarks on Political Participation in the Roman Republic." In Marco Simón, F., Pina Polo, F., and Remesmal Rodríguez, J. Repúblicas y ciudadanos: modelos de participación cívica en el mundo antiguo. Barcelona: Universitat de Barcelona. 221–34.
———. 2011. "The Rise of the Consular as a Social Type in the Third and Second Centuries BC." In Beck, H. et al. eds. Consuls and Res Publica: Holding High Office in the Roman Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 211–31.
———. 2016. "The Senatorial Economics of Status in the Late Republic." In Beck, H., Jehne, M., and Serrati, J. eds. Money and Power in the Roman Republic. Bruxelles: Éditions Latomus. 188–207.
Kron, G. 2008. "The Much Maligned Peasant. Comparative Perspectives on the Productivity of the Small Farmer in Classical Antiquity." In de Ligt and Northwood, eds. 71–119.
———. 2017. "The Diversification and Intensification of Italian Agriculture: The Complementary Roles of the Small and Wealthy Farmer." In de Haas and Tol, eds. 112–40.
Launaro, A. 2017. "Something Old, Something New: Social and Economic Developments in the Countryside of Roman Italy between Republic and Empire." In de Haas and Tol, eds. 85–111.
Laurence, R. 1999. The Roads of Roman Italy: Mobility and Cultural Change. London: Routledge.
Lintott, A. 1999. The Constitution of the Roman Republic. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Lomas, K. 2012. "The Weakest Link: Elite Social Networks in Republican Italy." In Roselaar, S. ed. Processes of Integration and Identity Formation in the Roman Republic. Leiden: Brill. 197–214.
MacMullen, R. 1980. "How Many Romans Voted?" Athenaeum 58: 454–57.
Morley, N. 1996. Metropolis and Hinterland: The City of Rome and the Italian Economy, 200 B.C.–A.D. 200. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Morstein-Marx, R. 1998. "Publicity, Popularity and Patronage in the 'Commentariolum Petitionis'." ClAnt 17: 259–88.
Mouritsen, H. 1998. Italian Unification: A Study in Ancient and Modern Historiography, London: Institute of Classical Studies.
———. 2001. Plebs and Politics in the Late Roman Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 2017. Politics in the Roman Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nicolet, C. 1980. The World of the Citizen in Republican Rome. Trans. by P. S. Falla. London: Batsford.
North, J. A. 1990. "Democratic Politics in Republican Rome." P&P 126: 3–21.
Perrin, B. 1921. Plutarch's Lives, Volume X. London: Heinemann.
Phillips, D. A. 2004. "Voter Turnout in Consular Elections." AHB 18: 48–60.
Rafferty, D. 2017. "Cisalpine Gaul as a Consular Province in the late Republic." Historia 66: 147–72.
Ramsey, J. T. 2018. "The Date of the Consular Elections in 63 B.C. and the Inception of Catiline's Conspiracy." HSCP 110: 213–69.
Rathbone, D. 2008. "Poor Peasants and Silent Sherds." In de Ligt and Northwood, eds. 305–32.
Rees, W. 2009. "'Ex Italia convenerunt' (Cic. Dom. 12.30): Italian Participation in Roman Political Life (133–44 BC)." In Keaveney, A. and Earnshaw-Brown, L. eds. The Italians on the Land: Changing Perspectives on Republican Italy Then and Now, Newcastle upon Tyne: Cambridge Scholars Publishing. 85–106.
Rich, J. W. 1983. "The Supposed Roman Manpower Shortage of the Later Second Century B.C." Historia 32: 287–331.
Richardson, L. 1992. A New Topographical Dictionary of Ancient Rome. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Rollinger, C. 2020. "Networking the Res Publica: Social Network Analysis and Republican Rome." In Kerschbaumer, F. et al. eds. The Power of Networks: Prospects of Historical Network Research. New York: Routledge.
Rosenstein, N. 1995. "Sorting out the Lot in Republican Rome." AJP 116: 43–75.
———. 2004. Rome at War: Farms, Families, and Death in the Middle Republic. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
———. 2006. "Aristocratic Values." In Rosenstein, N. and Morstein-Marx, R. eds. A Companion to the Roman Republic. Malden: Blackwell. 365–82.
———. 2008. "Aristocrats and Agriculture in the Middle and Late Republic." JRS 98: 1–26.
Scheidel, W. 2008. "Roman Population Size: The Logic of the Debate." In de Ligt and Northwood, eds. 17–70.
Scheidel, W., and Meeks, E. 2013. "ORBIS: The Stanford Geospatial Network Model of the Roman World." Accessed 20 July 2020. http://orbis.stanford.edu/.
Shackleton Bailey, D. R. 1965. Cicero: Letters to Atticus: Volume 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 2001. Cicero: Letters to Friends, Volume 2. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Spurr, M. S. 1986. Arable Cultivation in Roman Italy, c. 200 B.C.–c. A.D. 100. London: SPRS.
Staveley, E. S. 1972. Greek and Roman Voting and Elections. London: Thames & Hudson.
Tarpin, M. 2019. "La paperasse avant le papier: Enregistrement, déclarations, identité, contrôles à Rome." In Borlenghi, A. et al. eds. Voter en Grèce, à Rome et en Gaule: Pratiques, lieux et finalités. Lyon: MOM Éditions.
Tatum, W. J. 2018. Quintus Cicero: A Brief Handbook on Canvassing for Office. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Taylor, L. R. 1966. Roman Voting Assemblies: From the Hannibalic War to the Dictatorship of Caesar. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
———. 2013. The Voting Districts of the Roman Republic: The Thirty-five Urban and Rural Tribes. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Temin, P. 2013. The Roman Market Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Veyne, P. 1992. Bread and Circuses: Historical Sociology and Political Pluralism. Trans. by B. Pearce. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Wallace-Hadrill, A. 1989. "Patronage in Roman Society: From Republic to Empire." In Wallace-Hadrill, A. ed. Patronage in Ancient Society. London: Routledge. 63–87.
Yakobson, A. 1992. "Petitio et Largitio: Popular Participation in the Centuriate Assembly of the Late Republic." JRS 82: 32–52.
———. 1999. Elections and Electioneering in Rome. Stuttgart: Steiner.

Footnotes

1. Loeb translation (Perrin 1921).

2. Throughout this article, "Class" (with a capital C) refers to the five voting Classes established at each census. On the demographics of these see below.

3. Quotes from Gelzer 1969: 139 and Yakobson 1999: 228 respectively. As has often been noted, Gelzer here refers to social relationships of all types and not simply clientela.

5. Mouritsen 2001: 37n75 (illiteracy), 26–30 (restricted size of the voting enclosure); Mouritsen 2017: 28 (procedures and lack of compensation).

14. Phillips 2004; cf. Yakobson 1999: 49n78. However, Jehne 2006: 224n23 notes that there was no successive voting in tribal elections, as for aediles and quaestors.

18. Loeb translation (Shackleton Bailey 2001).

21. I do not intend to discuss Comment. Pet. at length. I rely heavily on Tatum's excellent recent commentary (Tatum 2018) although it is hopefully clear at which points I go beyond it.

25. For the remainder of this paragraph see Tatum 2018: 224–32.

27. The tribes (tribus) "were local divisions of the citizens," four urban and thirty-one rural; "all the ager Romanus, that is, all the territory of the Roman state not in public possession (ager publicus) was assigned to citizens in the rural tribes" (Taylor 2013: 3).

28. See Nicolet 1980: 53–60 on the five hierarchical census Classes and Livy 1.43 for how they supposedly operated under the kings. The 70 First Class centuries were clearly organized on tribal lines, while tribal units in the lower Classes were probably combined into centuries on an ad hoc basis. The argument of Lintott 1999: 59–60 that "centuriae were permanent, not ad hoc combinations on the day of the vote" is not reflected by the evidence he presents. While Comment. Pet. 18 does indeed say some men can win tribes or centuries, section 29 implies that the centuries in question are those of the equites, not of the lower Classes.

30. See Staveley 1972: 149–74 for an overview, although some details are challenged by Hall 1964 and Hall 1998. See further Taylor 1966: 34–35, 47–58, 90–100.

31. Hall 1964: 288–90 and Staveley 1972: 182–86 argue voters continued to vote for two candidates after one place had been filled (with which I agree) but could not vote for the returned candidate. This may be the case, but it forgets that office was an honos: in voting, voters were doing honor to a fellow citizen more than giving him power, a fact that suggests they would not lightly be deprived of the chance to honor a man who had already been elected. On election to office as both honos and "honor" see Rosenstein 2006 (especially 371) and Hölkeskamp 2010: 90–91.

32. Mouritsen 2001: 105 is probably correct that voters could vote for multiple candidates, up to the number the comitia was choosing, but could enter fewer if they wished and their vote still count as valid; cf. Hall 1964: 297–300.

33. Staveley 1972: 188–90 and Hall 1998: 29 both understand the time taken to count the votes is the real problem. Assuming voting at the rate of fifteen per minute and with far lower turnout than I argue for, Staveley still arrives at praetorian elections taking as long as 24 hours. Even if we allow that counting began as soon as the first voting basket was filled (which Staveley does not), a praetorian election decided by the Fourth Class and with only 20,000 citizens voting would still (by my calculations) last more than 13 hours. The practical solution is that multiple simultaneous counts took place for each voting unit, to allow the votes to be counted as quickly as possible. This is consistent with Cic. Red. Sen. 17, where Cicero says he was primus custos (implying there were several custodes); cf. Cic. Pis. 11.

35. Yakobson 1999: 49n77, with references to earlier scholarship.

36. For an introduction to the debate, see Scheidel 2008.

37. Rich 1983: 305–16, who argues for HS25,000.

40. See particularly the Oxford Roman Economy Project (romaneconomy.ox.ac.uk) and the accompanying monograph series, Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy.

45. Temin 2013: 143 (price of land).

46. Quote from Yakobson 1999: 47; Davenport 2019: 35–37. Polybius's figures for Roman cavalry numbers are not relevant to this discussion.

47. Rosenstein 2004: 185–86, arguing that the assidui must have been at least a sizable majority of the citizen body, even if that proportion was reduced by the later second century.

50. The proletarii, however, lumped as they were into a single century, were not worth the attention of candidates for their votes.

51. Locally influential men might themselves be of high family in Rome. Martin Jehne notes the relatively late move of consulars living largely on their estates to the Ciceronian model of full-time politics in the City: Jehne 2011. Such men surely retained strong local connections.

56. Loeb translation (Shackleton Bailey 1965).

57. For a contrary view of this evidence, see Mouritsen 1998: 97n35, Mouritsen 2001: 120–22.

58. For a detailed discussion of both elite and smallholder marketing, see Morley 1996: 159–74 and the chapters in de Haas and Tol 2017. See also Laurence 1999: 136–47 on travel more broadly. As by far the largest city in the peninsula, Rome was itself the principal market for many goods across much of Italy.

60. On the labor requirements of grain farming, see Spurr 1986: 135–40.

61. Rathbone 2008: 309, 321–23 argues that medium-sized farms (i.e., those in the range c. 20–50 iugera) could support a couple of slaves. On the productivity and comparative affluence of Roman small farmers see Kron 2008.

62. Spurr 1986: 66, 139. The date of harvest varied with location; temperate areas near the sea harvested earlier than inland regions. The demand for labor in the countryside probably also drew potential voters from the cities.

63. Although see now Ramsey 2018.

64. This has not, to my knowledge, been seriously proposed in relation to Rome, but is a potential logical objection based on comparable political cultures.

71. See for instance Tatum 2018: 25: "Each political figure was the centre of an intricate and potentially fragile network of varied associations, the totality of which demanded assiduous attention and no part of which could ever be taken for granted—not least because too many members of his coalition were also obliged to others." This is true, but if we move our focus from the political figure to ordinary Roman citizens enmeshed in those same networks, we begin to understand what factors impinged on the voters' choice. On elite networks see now Rollinger 2020, who concretizes Tatum's general statements.

73. Text and translation from Tatum 2018.

78. On the importance of reciprocal favors in Roman social relations see Lomas 2012, who focuses particularly on hospitium; the concern with obtaining and repaying favors has too often been thought of as purely an elite phenomenon.

80. North 1990: 6–7; this theory held that all politics was controlled by stable factions of "a narrow hereditary oligarchy."

81. Cox 1984. It is to be lamented that the Roman electoral system is not commonly studied in modern political science; it would be a fascinating data point.

Share

Footnotes

  1. 1. Loeb translation (Perrin 1921).

  2. 2. Throughout this article, "Class" (with a capital C) refers to the five voting Classes established at each census. On the demographics of these see below.

  3. 3. Quotes from Gelzer 1969: 139 and Yakobson 1999: 228 respectively. As has often been noted, Gelzer here refers to social relationships of all types and not simply clientela.

  4. 4. Mouritsen 2001: 32.

  5. 5. Mouritsen 2001: 37n75 (illiteracy), 26–30 (restricted size of the voting enclosure); Mouritsen 2017: 28 (procedures and lack of compensation).

  6. 6. Mouritsen 2001: 95.

  7. 7. Mouritsen 2017: 57.

  8. 8. MacMullen 1980; Jehne 2006.

  9. 9. Yakobson 1992; Yakobson 1999.

  10. 10. Phillips 2004; Rees 2009.

  11. 11. Mouritsen 2017: 55.

  12. 12. Richardson 1992: 340; Coarelli 2001.

  13. 13. MacMullen 1980: 454.

  14. 14. Phillips 2004; cf. Yakobson 1999: 49n78. However, Jehne 2006: 224n23 notes that there was no successive voting in tribal elections, as for aediles and quaestors.

  15. 15. Mouritsen 2001: 29.

  16. 16. Tarpin 2019.

  17. 17. Mouritsen 2001: 30–31.

  18. 18. Loeb translation (Shackleton Bailey 2001).

  19. 19. Nicolet 1980: 291.

  20. 20. Mouritsen 2001: 31.

  21. 21. I do not intend to discuss Comment. Pet. at length. I rely heavily on Tatum's excellent recent commentary (Tatum 2018) although it is hopefully clear at which points I go beyond it.

  22. 22. Morstein-Marx 1998: 260–61.

  23. 23. Tatum 2018: 218.

  24. 24. MacMullen 1980: 457.

  25. 25. For the remainder of this paragraph see Tatum 2018: 224–32.

  26. 26. Yakobson 1999: 84–90; Tatum 2018: 42–43, 243–44.

  27. 27. The tribes (tribus) "were local divisions of the citizens," four urban and thirty-one rural; "all the ager Romanus, that is, all the territory of the Roman state not in public possession (ager publicus) was assigned to citizens in the rural tribes" (Taylor 2013: 3).

  28. 28. See Nicolet 1980: 53–60 on the five hierarchical census Classes and Livy 1.43 for how they supposedly operated under the kings. The 70 First Class centuries were clearly organized on tribal lines, while tribal units in the lower Classes were probably combined into centuries on an ad hoc basis. The argument of Lintott 1999: 59–60 that "centuriae were permanent, not ad hoc combinations on the day of the vote" is not reflected by the evidence he presents. While Comment. Pet. 18 does indeed say some men can win tribes or centuries, section 29 implies that the centuries in question are those of the equites, not of the lower Classes.

  29. 29. Yakobson 1999: 50–51.

  30. 30. See Staveley 1972: 149–74 for an overview, although some details are challenged by Hall 1964 and Hall 1998. See further Taylor 1966: 34–35, 47–58, 90–100.

  31. 31. Hall 1964: 288–90 and Staveley 1972: 182–86 argue voters continued to vote for two candidates after one place had been filled (with which I agree) but could not vote for the returned candidate. This may be the case, but it forgets that office was an honos: in voting, voters were doing honor to a fellow citizen more than giving him power, a fact that suggests they would not lightly be deprived of the chance to honor a man who had already been elected. On election to office as both honos and "honor" see Rosenstein 2006 (especially 371) and Hölkeskamp 2010: 90–91.

  32. 32. Mouritsen 2001: 105 is probably correct that voters could vote for multiple candidates, up to the number the comitia was choosing, but could enter fewer if they wished and their vote still count as valid; cf. Hall 1964: 297–300.

  33. 33. Staveley 1972: 188–90 and Hall 1998: 29 both understand the time taken to count the votes is the real problem. Assuming voting at the rate of fifteen per minute and with far lower turnout than I argue for, Staveley still arrives at praetorian elections taking as long as 24 hours. Even if we allow that counting began as soon as the first voting basket was filled (which Staveley does not), a praetorian election decided by the Fourth Class and with only 20,000 citizens voting would still (by my calculations) last more than 13 hours. The practical solution is that multiple simultaneous counts took place for each voting unit, to allow the votes to be counted as quickly as possible. This is consistent with Cic. Red. Sen. 17, where Cicero says he was primus custos (implying there were several custodes); cf. Cic. Pis. 11.

  34. 34. Yakobson 1999: 48–54.

  35. 35. Yakobson 1999: 49n77, with references to earlier scholarship.

  36. 36. For an introduction to the debate, see Scheidel 2008.

  37. 37. Rich 1983: 305–16, who argues for HS25,000.

  38. 38. Rathbone 2008: 308; Rees 2009: 91–93, 102–4.

  39. 39. Rees 2009: 92–93.

  40. 40. See particularly the Oxford Roman Economy Project (romaneconomy.ox.ac.uk) and the accompanying monograph series, Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy.

  41. 41. Launaro 2017: 105.

  42. 42. Rosenstein 2008: 8.

  43. 43. Kron 2017: 125–27.

  44. 44. Kron 2017: 123.

  45. 45. Temin 2013: 143 (price of land).

  46. 46. Quote from Yakobson 1999: 47; Davenport 2019: 35–37. Polybius's figures for Roman cavalry numbers are not relevant to this discussion.

  47. 47. Rosenstein 2004: 185–86, arguing that the assidui must have been at least a sizable majority of the citizen body, even if that proportion was reduced by the later second century.

  48. 48. Morstein-Marx 1998: 262n20.

  49. 49. Yakobson 1999: 52.

  50. 50. The proletarii, however, lumped as they were into a single century, were not worth the attention of candidates for their votes.

  51. 51. Locally influential men might themselves be of high family in Rome. Martin Jehne notes the relatively late move of consulars living largely on their estates to the Ciceronian model of full-time politics in the City: Jehne 2011. Such men surely retained strong local connections.

  52. 52. Laurence 1999: 81–82; Scheidel and Meeks 2013.

  53. 53. Goodchild 2007: 166–70; de Haas 2017: 68–69.

  54. 54. Bispham 2007: 409–13.

  55. 55. Rafferty 2017: 165–68.

  56. 56. Loeb translation (Shackleton Bailey 1965).

  57. 57. For a contrary view of this evidence, see Mouritsen 1998: 97n35, Mouritsen 2001: 120–22.

  58. 58. For a detailed discussion of both elite and smallholder marketing, see Morley 1996: 159–74 and the chapters in de Haas and Tol 2017. See also Laurence 1999: 136–47 on travel more broadly. As by far the largest city in the peninsula, Rome was itself the principal market for many goods across much of Italy.

  59. 59. Erdkamp 2008: 421–24; Isayev 2017: 29–32, 212–13.

  60. 60. On the labor requirements of grain farming, see Spurr 1986: 135–40.

  61. 61. Rathbone 2008: 309, 321–23 argues that medium-sized farms (i.e., those in the range c. 20–50 iugera) could support a couple of slaves. On the productivity and comparative affluence of Roman small farmers see Kron 2008.

  62. 62. Spurr 1986: 66, 139. The date of harvest varied with location; temperate areas near the sea harvested earlier than inland regions. The demand for labor in the countryside probably also drew potential voters from the cities.

  63. 63. Although see now Ramsey 2018.

  64. 64. This has not, to my knowledge, been seriously proposed in relation to Rome, but is a potential logical objection based on comparable political cultures.

  65. 65. Yakobson 1999: 98–101.

  66. 66. Taylor 2013: 98; cf. Morstein-Marx 1998: 280.

  67. 67. Veyne 1992: 219–24; Yakobson 1992: 35–41.

  68. 68. MacMullen 1980: 457.

  69. 69. Jehne 2000.

  70. 70. Wallace-Hadrill 1989: 77.

  71. 71. See for instance Tatum 2018: 25: "Each political figure was the centre of an intricate and potentially fragile network of varied associations, the totality of which demanded assiduous attention and no part of which could ever be taken for granted—not least because too many members of his coalition were also obliged to others." This is true, but if we move our focus from the political figure to ordinary Roman citizens enmeshed in those same networks, we begin to understand what factors impinged on the voters' choice. On elite networks see now Rollinger 2020, who concretizes Tatum's general statements.

  72. 72. Tatum 2018: 245–47.

  73. 73. Text and translation from Tatum 2018.

  74. 74. Shackleton-Bailey 1965: 350–51; Tatum 2018: 230–31.

  75. 75. See also Tatum 2018: 27–28.

  76. 76. Jehne 2016.

  77. 77. Feig Vishnia 2012: 117–19.

  78. 78. On the importance of reciprocal favors in Roman social relations see Lomas 2012, who focuses particularly on hospitium; the concern with obtaining and repaying favors has too often been thought of as purely an elite phenomenon.

  79. 79. Tatum 2018: 224–26, 288–89 with further bibliography; Feig Vishnia 2012: 139–41.

  80. 80. North 1990: 6–7; this theory held that all politics was controlled by stable factions of "a narrow hereditary oligarchy."

  81. 81. Cox 1984. It is to be lamented that the Roman electoral system is not commonly studied in modern political science; it would be a fascinating data point.

  82. 82. Taylor 1966: 111; Rosenstein 1995: 58–62; Mouritsen 2017: 45–50.

  83. 83. Mouritsen 2017: 49 and 45, respectively.